Geek Think: Housing Boom Phase Diagrams

Warning, this article may only be interesting to geeks. If you are not a geek, the DELETE button is on the upper right hand corner of your keyboard.

Thought it would be useful for some readers to give you a more formal statement of the property market analysis in the previous entry.

As my old friends know, I am a big fan of making sure you distinguish between asset markets and flow markets when thinking about the economy. The reason is pretty simple. GDP is a number of about $12 trillion, chump change in comparison with our $155 trillion asset market, including $105 trillion in financial assets and $50 trillion in real estate and other tangible (George Carlin) stuff, according to the most recent Fed Flow of Funds reports.

Bottom line: if a policy does not impact the asset markets it does not matter.


Aside: This is no different than asking whether the earth orbits the sun or the other way around. Most people know the sun is the big dog in this story, therefore the earth orbits the sun. Actually this is not true. You can get a free drink at a cocktail party by telling people that actually both the sun and the earth rotate the center of mass of the sun-earth system, which is a point inside the sun but not its center. The end.

This is important because almost all of what passes for macroeconomic analysis today is simply descriptions of who is spending how much money in the GDP accounts. That analysis leads these thinkers to make big mistakes, which gives us great opportunities to make money.

Regarding real estate, take a look at the following diagram.

Housing Boom Dynamics.GIF

In this diagram, the graph on the upper left represents the asset market in which the price P of the existing housing stock, K, is determined.

The graph on the upper right represents the new construction (flow) market in which the price of an existing home interacts with the marginal costs of contractors to determine the number of homes or buildings they are willing to build, which we denote by lower-case k.

The lower right graph is simply a device for bringing big K and little k together on the same graph, which I have placed in the lower left. That is where all the action takes place.

Start with housing stock K(0) and demand for homes D(0) which determine the initial price of a house at P(0) in the upper left graph. A drop in interet rates increases the number of homes demanded at each price, creates an excess demand for homes, and pushes the price of an existing home up to P(1).

In the new construction market in the upper right graph, the higher home price results in more homes being built per year, k(1), than was the case at higher interest rates.

Now the hard part. The graph in the lower left is a phase diagram, a concept we can use to help think about dynamics. The critical concept is the stationary state line descending from the origin downward and to the right. That line represents combinations of K(t) and k(t) that leave the existing housing stock unchanged. This will happen when the construction of new homes, k(t), is just big enough to replace the number of homes that have worn out through depreciation (you know, like when your teen-agers come home). I have assumed that delta percent of existing homes die each year through depreciation. For example, if a home lasts 50 years, then delta would be 2% per year.

Assume we start at K(0) and k(0), which is a point on the line described above, i.e., we start in a situation where the housing stock is neither growing now shrinking. I can do this–it is my chart!

Now lower interest rates. The higher demand in the upper left graph increases the price to P(1), which increases housing construction in the upper right to k(1). But at k(1), we are building more houses than needed to replace the ones wearing out. Therefore the housing stock is growing. In fact, a little thought and 2 glasses of wine will convince you that all the points downward and to the left of the line in the lower left graph represent situations of a growing housing stock. In fact, the distance from the line indicates how fast it is rising or falling. Conversely, all points to the right of the line represent a shrinking housing stock. The housing stock will continue to grow until construction and depreciation are once more equal and the housing stock is in a new stationary state. (Geek note: Ludwig von Mises would have referred to such points as evenly rotating. Richard Dawkins would call them ESS, or evolutionary stable systems.)

A drop in interest rates will make a permanent increase in housing prices but, over time, the growing housing stock will mitigate some of the price and construction pressure, which means the initial burst of activity, and possibly of price, are likely to moderate somewhat over time. To an information theorist, the initial spike in price is a way of amplifying the initial information signal that housing is now scarce in order to get everybody’s attention so they get out their hammers and build more houses.

So interest-rate induced housing inflation is largely a one-time event. It is not property inflation. It is not a housing bubble.

Housing inflation, as opposed to one-time increases in home prices, happens when there is a continuous increase in demand caused, for example, by systematically inflationary monetary policy. We do not have that today.

Housing bubbles pop when a sudden reversal of interest rates, or a sudden reduction in the availability of mortgage financing, causes a sudden, one-time, drop in demand. I don’t think that is going to happen either. Inflation today is likely to remain low for some time.

Conclusion: There were good reasons why home prices increased over the past two years. But don’t get caught in either the trap of believing they will continue to rise, or that there is an unavoidable housing bubble. Prices will be relatively flat over the next year.

Final geek note–I promise. The construct of present values, which underlies the construction of the stock demand curve in the upper left quadrant of our story, and we use all the time in finance, is weak stuff. Usually done by using the discount rate, a single number that is supposed to represent the opportunity cost of alternative assets during the life of the house. What we should use is estimates of the rental value of the house for each future year, each discounted by the relevant expected discount rate for that period, which you can approximate by calculating expected forward interest rates rom adjacent bond yields. When the shapes of the cash flow streams we are analyzing (here determined by the choice of depreciation rate) are different from the shapes of the cash flows of the bond we are using to measure interest rates, this causes problems. Especially true for the housing stock, which certainly has a duration longer than any government bond today.

JR

Share and Enjoy: These icons link to social bookmarking sites where readers can share and discover new web pages.
  • MisterWong
  • Y!GG
  • Webnews
  • Digg
  • del.icio.us
  • StumbleUpon
  • Reddit
This entry was posted in All. Bookmark the permalink.